Change search
Link to record
Permanent link

Direct link
Nekoei, Arash
Publications (10 of 11) Show all publications
Cederlöf, J., Fredriksson, P., Nekoei, A. & Seim, D. (2025). Mandatory Notice of Layoff, Job Search, and Efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 140(1), 585-633
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Mandatory Notice of Layoff, Job Search, and Efficiency
2025 (English)In: Quarterly Journal of Economics, ISSN 0033-5533, E-ISSN 1531-4650, Vol. 140, no 1, p. 585-633Article in journal (Refereed) Published
Abstract [en]

In all OECD countries, mandatory notice (MN) policies require firms to inform workers in advance of a layoff. In our theoretical framework, MN helps workers avoid unemployment and find better jobs by encouraging them to search for a new job while still employed, thereby increasing future production. The magnitude of this production gain depends on the relative effectiveness of search while employed versus unemployed. But on-the-job search and diminished work incentives reduce current production. If future gains outweigh current production losses, longer advance notice improves production efficiency. If not, Coasian bargaining predicts that firms offer a larger severance instead of longer notice. With bargaining, the sole efficiency loss of MN is due to delayed separations of unproductive job matches. We test these predictions using novel Swedish administrative data on layoff notifications. Workers eligible for extended MN receive longer notice and larger severance, resulting in less exposure to nonemployment spells and higher-paying jobs. These favorable labor market outcomes are solely due to longer notice; in contrast, larger severance delays job finding and has no impact on wages. We also show that advance notice replaces job search while unemployed with more effective search while employed. On the production side, we document a productivity drop among notified workers and estimate a production loss due to delayed separations. Using our estimates of production gains and losses to evaluate the overall production efficiency, we conclude that the gains of MN seem to outweigh the losses.

National Category
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-239898 (URN)10.1093/qje/qjae029 (DOI)001345936400001 ()2-s2.0-85215851668 (Scopus ID)
Available from: 2025-02-27 Created: 2025-02-27 Last updated: 2025-02-27Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Seim, D. (2022). How Do Inheritances Shape Wealth Inequality? Theory and Evidence from Sweden. The Review of Economic Studies, 90(1), 463-498
Open this publication in new window or tab >>How Do Inheritances Shape Wealth Inequality? Theory and Evidence from Sweden
2022 (English)In: The Review of Economic Studies, ISSN 0034-6527, E-ISSN 1467-937X, Vol. 90, no 1, p. 463-498Article in journal (Refereed) Published
Abstract [en]

This article aims to measure and understand the role of inheritances in shaping wealth inequality. We use a quasi-experimental design and Swedish administrative data to document that the average heir depletes her inheritance within a decade while the inheritances of wealthy heirs remain intact. These different depletion rates are not due to different consumption or labour supply responses but due to different rates of return on inherited wealth. Upon their receipt, inheritances reduce relative measures of wealth inequality, such as top shares or percentile ratios. Theoretically, this reduction in inequality could be due to either a compressed inheritance distribution or similar chances of having wealthy parents (high intergenerational mobility). Empirically, the first force is more significant in Sweden. Within a decade, however, the effect is reversed: inheritances increase wealth inequality since the different depletion rates widen the inequality in inherited wealth over time. This implies that inheritance taxation can reduce long run wealth inequality only through the taxation of wealthy heirs.

Keywords
Wealth inequality, inheritances, MPC, D31, E21, H20
National Category
Economics and Business
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-204739 (URN)10.1093/restud/rdac016 (DOI)000790916200001 ()2-s2.0-85169814529 (Scopus ID)
Available from: 2022-05-23 Created: 2022-05-23 Last updated: 2024-10-16Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. (2022). The measurement of labor supply using March CPS: A cautionary tale. Economics Letters, 216, Article ID 110512.
Open this publication in new window or tab >>The measurement of labor supply using March CPS: A cautionary tale
2022 (English)In: Economics Letters, ISSN 0165-1765, E-ISSN 1873-7374, Vol. 216, article id 110512Article in journal (Refereed) Published
Abstract [en]

I document evidence of a systematic bias in the widely-used estimate of annual hours worked using the Current Population Survey. The bias stems from multiplying the number of weeks worked by the median – instead of the mean – of weekly working hours. Theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that this bias leads to an overestimation of annual hours.

Keywords
Labor supply
National Category
Economics and Business
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-216143 (URN)10.1016/j.econlet.2022.110512 (DOI)000829780800001 ()2-s2.0-85130030150 (Scopus ID)
Available from: 2023-04-05 Created: 2023-04-05 Last updated: 2023-04-05Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Sinn, F. (2021). HERSTORY: The Rise of Self-Made Women.
Open this publication in new window or tab >>HERSTORY: The Rise of Self-Made Women
2021 (English)Other (Other academic)
Abstract [en]

We document the evolution of women's status across the globe and throughout recorded history.We first construct a new database of seven million notable individuals (Human BiographicalRecord). We then measure women's status as women's share among the most prominent fractionof population that allows comparison across time and space. The records show no long-run trendin women's share in recorded history. Historically, women's power has been a side-effect ofnepotism: the more important family connections, the higher the women's share. But self-madewomen began to rise among the writers in the 17th century before a broader take off started withthe 1800 birth cohort: first among artists and scholars, followed by elected politicians, and finallyappointed politicians. The first wave among writers emerged when informal humanist educationand new public spheres shaped a supply of literary women, who met the demand of a new femalereading public. A strong writer wave predicts a stronger takeoff of self-made women in the 19thcentury. This effect has persisted and created cross-country divergence. 

Publisher
p. 33
Series
CEPR Discussion Paper Series ; DP15736
Keywords
Women emancipation, Big Data
National Category
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-203322 (URN)
Available from: 2022-03-28 Created: 2022-03-28 Last updated: 2022-03-29Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Sinn, F. (2021). Human Biographical Record (HBR).
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Human Biographical Record (HBR)
2021 (English)Report (Other academic)
Abstract [en]

We construct a new dataset of more than seven million notable individuals across recorded human history, the Human Biographical Record (HBR). With Wikidata as the backbone, HBR adds further information from various digital sources, including Wikipedia in all 292 languages. Machine learning and text analysis combine the sources and extract information on date and place of birth and death, gender, occupation, education, and family background. This paper discusses HBR's construction and its completeness, coverage, accuracy, and also its strength and weakness relative to prior datasets. HBR is the first part of a larger project, the human record project that we briefly introduce.

Series
CEPR Discussion Paper Series ; 15825
Keywords
Bid data, machine learning, economic history
National Category
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-191091 (URN)
Available from: 2021-03-08 Created: 2021-03-08 Last updated: 2022-02-25Bibliographically approved
Landais, C., Nekoei, A., Nilsson, P., Seim, D. & Spinnewijn, J. (2021). Risk-Based Selection in Unemployment Insurance: Evidence and Implications. The American Economic Review, 111(4), 1315-1355
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Risk-Based Selection in Unemployment Insurance: Evidence and Implications
Show others...
2021 (English)In: The American Economic Review, ISSN 0002-8282, E-ISSN 1944-7981, Vol. 111, no 4, p. 1315-1355Article in journal (Refereed) Published
Abstract [en]

This paper studies whether adverse selection can rationalize a universal mandate for unemployment insurance (UI). Building on a unique feature of the unemployment policy in Sweden, where workers can opt for supplemental UI coverage above a minimum mandate, we provide the first direct evidence for adverse selection in UI and derive its implications for UI design. We find that the unemployment risk is more than twice as high for workers who buy supplemental coverage. Exploiting variation in risk and prices, we show how 25-30 percent of this correlation is driven by risk-based selection, with the remainder driven by moral hazard. Due to the moral hazard and despite the adverse selection we find that mandating the supplemental coverage to individuals with low willingness-to-pay would be suboptimal. We show under which conditions a design leaving choice to workers would dominate a UI system with a single mandate. In this design, using a subsidy for supplemental coverage is optimal and complementary to the use of a minimum mandate.

National Category
Economics and Business
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-193044 (URN)10.1257/aer.20180820 (DOI)000635983300008 ()
Available from: 2021-05-10 Created: 2021-05-10 Last updated: 2022-02-25Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Sinn, F. (2021). Social Inclusion: Definition and Measurement.
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Social Inclusion: Definition and Measurement
2021 (English)Other (Other academic)
Abstract [en]

We define social inclusion (SI) as the equality of success rate conditional on circumstances, i.e., inherent characteristics and family background. We measure SI using an aggregator, social inclusion function, e.g., mutual information or the share of success variance unexplained by circumstances. Another interpretation of SI is the unpredictability of success using circumstances. We discuss the role of out-of-sample prediction and machine learning in estimating SI, which we then illustrate in three complementary applications. The first two applications document global SI using a small set of circumstances: the inclusiveness of the elite in long-run history and contemporary SI of education. The first application measures the inclusiveness of the elite in the long-run history and reveals the exceptional high SI in the 20th century. The second application estimates contemporary SI of literacy across 68 countries and shows that country of birth is an obstacle to SI as much as family background. The third application estimate SI in Sweden today using a rich set of circumstances from administrative data. In order: Gender, nationality of parents, and their income/education restrict inclusion whereas the place of birth plays almost no role.

Series
SSRN Research Paper Series ; July 26, 2021
Keywords
inequality, inter-generational mobility, social mobility
National Category
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-203321 (URN)10.2139/ssrn.3893489 (DOI)
Available from: 2022-03-28 Created: 2022-03-28 Last updated: 2022-03-30Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Weber, A. (2020). Seven Facts about Temporary Layoffs.
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Seven Facts about Temporary Layoffs
2020 (English)Report (Other academic)
Abstract [en]

We establish seven facts about temporary layoffs (TL), whose employers communicated an anticipated recall date at layoff: (1) The higher the current TL share at firm/industry-level, the higher (lower) the future recall (layoff) likelihood for both temporary and permanent layoffs (employees); (2) TL is more prevalent in: the upper-middle part of the wage distribution, (3-4) in mass layoffs and recessions; (5) The later the communicated recall date, the lower the accepted new-job wage, unconditional and conditional on non-employment duration; (6) TLs' new-job hazard rate (wage) jumps (drops) when recall likelihood falls; (7) Extending unemployment benefits increases separations in recall-intense sectors.

Series
CEPR Discussion Paper Series ; 14845
National Category
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-191092 (URN)
Available from: 2021-03-08 Created: 2021-03-08 Last updated: 2022-02-25Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Weber, A. (2017). Does Extending Unemployment Benefits Improve Job Quality?. The American Economic Review, 107(2), 527-561
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Does Extending Unemployment Benefits Improve Job Quality?
2017 (English)In: The American Economic Review, ISSN 0002-8282, E-ISSN 1944-7981, Vol. 107, no 2, p. 527-561Article in journal (Refereed) Published
Abstract [en]

Contrary to standard search models predictions, past studies have not found a positive effect of unemployment insurance (UI) on reemployment wages. We estimate a positive UI wage effect exploiting an age-based regression discontinuity design in Austria. A search model incorporating duration dependence predicts two countervailing forces: UI induces workers to seek higher-wage jobs, but reduces wages by lengthening unemployment. Matching-function heterogeneity plausibly generates a negative relationship between the UI unemployment-duration and wage effects, which holds empirically in our sample and across studies, reconciling disparate wage-effect estimates. Empirically, UI raises wages by improving reemployment firm quality and attenuating wage drops.

National Category
Economics and Business
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-142525 (URN)10.1257/aer.20150528 (DOI)000393993600008 ()
Available from: 2017-05-09 Created: 2017-05-09 Last updated: 2022-02-28Bibliographically approved
Nekoei, A. & Weber, A. (2015). Does extending unemployment benefits improve job quality?.
Open this publication in new window or tab >>Does extending unemployment benefits improve job quality?
2015 (English)Report (Other academic)
Abstract [en]

Contrary to standard search model predictions, prior studies failed to estimate a positive effect of unemployment insurance (UI) on reemployment wages. This paper estimates a positive UI wage effect exploiting an age-based regression discontinuity in Austrian administrative data. A search model incorporating duration dependence determines the UI wage effect as the balance between two offsetting forces: UI causes agents to seek higher-wage jobs, but also reduces wages by lengthening unemployment. This implies a negative relationship between the UI unemployment duration and wage effects, which holds empirically both in our sample and across studies, reconciling disparate wage-effect estimates. Empirically, UI raises wages by improving reemployment firms' quality and attenuating wage drops.

Series
CEPR Working Paper Series ; 10568
Keywords
job search, regression discontinuity design, unemployment insurance, wages
National Category
Economics
Research subject
Economics
Identifiers
urn:nbn:se:su:diva-125232 (URN)
Available from: 2016-01-08 Created: 2016-01-08 Last updated: 2022-02-23Bibliographically approved
Organisations

Search in DiVA

Show all publications